This article is on the role of the Reserve Bank of
India (RBI) in managing inflation, interest rates
and exchange rates. At stake are four inter-related
issues.
• First, what is the actual impact of growth in
money supply on inflation in India, with what lag,
and on what items?
• Second, what is the extent to which tighter credit
policies and harder interest rates affect domestic
demand, investment and growth?
• Third, in an environment of unprecedented
portfolio capital inflows, can we credibly regulate
the rate of exchange rate appreciation?
• Fourth, in a world where capital flows at the
click of a mouse, is it possible for a central bank
to simultaneously manage money supply, interest
rates and exchange rates, especially with huge
dollar inflows?
Let us examine these in reverse order. The answer to
the fourth is an unambiguous negative. In an open
economy with significant capital convertibility,
interest rates and exchange rates are co-determined.
One can’t fix one without affecting the other. And
this interdependence gets heightened in an
environment of massive capital inflows — where any
significant action to curb inflation by sharply
controlling money supply will rapidly affect the
other two variables. The greater the amount and
velocity of capital inflows, the bigger the problem
of controlling the triad — money supply, interest
and exchange rates.
The third issue is more complicated. To regulate the
rupee from appreciating ‘too much’, the RBI has to
steadily buy dollars. That immediately increases
money supply; and an inflation sensitive central
bank then has to suck out the extra money by
auctioning government securities (g-secs). It also
has to invest the dollars in US treasury bills
(t-bills). Since the interest on US t-bills is lower
than that on Indian g-secs, there is a hit on the
books. However, I have argued that the financial hit
is trivial compared to the effects of a sharply
appreciating rupee on the real economy. I believe
that the RBI has recently come around to the same
view — namely, intervene every so often to keep a
lid on exchange rate appreciation, and take a knock
on the cost of sterilisation. Which is why, despite
continuing inflows, the rupee has been of late
hovering around Rs.39.25, and not breached the Rs.39
mark.
In controlling exchange rate appreciation, a major
concern is credibility. How long can the RBI
consistently buy dollars, or wink at major banks to
do so? Can the pattern of intervention be gleaned by
major currency traders? And if the RBI lets go —
even for a few days — will the exchange rate
overshoot to intolerable levels?
Regarding the second issue, it is clear that the
tighter credit and harder interest rates are biting.
Consumer credit has reduced sharply; housing demand
is down; smaller firms are facing much higher
working capital costs; larger companies are cutting
their original investment plans. I wouldn’t be
surprised if we see a 1.5-2 percentage point drop in
the growth of industrial output. We are a stage
where high real interest is choking growth.
The relation between money supply growth and
inflation is the trickiest. There is no recent
definitive work that shows how growth in money
supply affects inflation; with what lag; and over
what class of goods and services. Our guideposts are
guesses, hunches and dated, shoddy empirical work.
Clearly money supply growth doesn’t affect the
prices of onions, potatoes, edible oils or foodgrain.
Nor does it affect globally traded minerals,
hydrocarbons or metals. My hunch is that inflation
in India is far more supply determined than what the
RBI believes.
In this milieu, there are no set formulae. We are in
uncharted waters. The RBI needs to craft finely
calibrated responses, learn from small errors, make
little moves every now and then; to ensure that
somehow the exchange rate doesn’t appreciate
alarmingly; that the interest rates get gradually
softened; and that money supply fuels growth instead
of inflation. It is a difficult act of continuously
adroit manoeuvring. The good thing is that the RBI
is learning the ropes. And realising that the times
require learning from unlearning… not from dead
certainties.
Published: Business World, November 2007